THE UK SHOULD WELCOME THE 15% MINIMUM CORPORATION TAX
BLOG 244
THE UK SHOULD WELCOME
THE 15% MINIMUM CORPORATION TAX
I have remarked before that I subscribe to CapEX
(which I highly recommend) which provides me with links to articles on current
affairs – some of which it commissions itself and some which are in other
publications. I am however puzzled as to
why they commissioned “Levelling down: signing up to the OECD tax plan risks
undermining key government policies”.
This was written by Connor Axiotes who describes himself as Director of
Communications at the Adam Smith Institute, (another think tank). My bewilderment is because the article seems
axiomatic of the well known saying, “Never let the facts get in the way of a
good story”.
Mr Axiotes is apparently a fan of freeports but
complains, “But there is an elephant in the room which could limit the Government’s
freedom to offer these [freeport] incentives.
The OECD’s Global Minimum Corporation Tax would impose a minimum rate of
taxation (set at 15%) on the revenues of international corporations”. He thinks that the UK rush to implement the
OECD proposals will undermine the levelling up agenda.
So where do I start?
First, the minimum tax (called Pillar II) is not a tax on the “revenues”
of international corporations. It is a
tax on the profits of the small number of multi-national enterprises
whose global turnover exceeds Eur 750million.
In other words, it is a top-up to corporation tax. As such, it has very little effect on
freeports because the freeport incentives do not include an exemption from
corporation tax. The tax incentives
primarily relate to import duties, import VAT and SDLT, none of which are
affected by the 15% cap. Indeed, as
corporation tax is based on the overall result of all of a company’s
activities, it is largely impractical to grant corporation tax relief on the
part earned in a freeport. It does have
some impact as the relief includes 100% first-year allowance on plant and
machinery (up to 30 September 2026 only) and accelerated structures and
buildings allowances, both of which reduce taxable profits – and both of which
can be disclaimed, i.e. the company can limit the claim in the year of
expenditure if the allowances would trigger the minimum tax in that year and
claim the balance in later years. The
benefit of early capital allowances is also likely to be fairly insignificant
in comparison with the exemption from employer’s NIC, the reduced planning restrictions
and the tax reliefs on imports.
Secondly, the government’s levelling up agenda has
very little to do with tax. It is to do
with bringing jobs to deprived areas, and while tax reliefs can encourage
business towards a particular area, they have fairly limited effect compared
with other factors.
Thirdly, the UK has not “rushed” to implement the
Pillar II proposals. These arose from
the OECD’s BEPS (Base Erosion and Profit Shifting) project which began in 2013,
virtually 10 years ago and in which both HMRC and UK large businesses have had
a heavy involvement throughout. The
minimum tax was first proposed in 2020.
The government, like most developed countries, signed up to the minimum
tax in 2021 and it issued a consultation paper on the implementation of the tax
in January 2022, which is over a year ago.
If Mr Axiotes regards that as rushing the legislation, I shudder to
think what his ideal timetable for introducing tax changes might be.
Fourthly – and probably most importantly – if the UK
does not introduce the legislation, the only one to suffer will be the UK. This is because the top-up tax is primarily
chargeable by the country in which the multinational group is based. However, if the group is based in a country
that has not implemented the tax, the countries in which the profits are
generated become entitled to charge the tax.
In other words, the UK legislation applies to only two categories of
earnings; worldwide earnings of UK multinationals and earnings of UK branches
of those foreign countries that have not implemented Pillar II. Not implementing it in the UK would exempt UK
earnings of UK multinationals (in most cases a very small part of their global
earnings) and UK earnings (if any) of overseas countries which also do not
implement it. Most of the benefit of
non-implementation would accrue to the US and other overseas governments in the
countries in which UK companies have operations, as they would become the
beneficiary of what otherwise would have been the UK’s right to impose the tax.
Fifthly, the UK government is not oblivious to the
fact that tax incentives can reduce taxable profits and so potentially trigger
the minimum tax. That is one of the
reasons why it is looking at replacing some tax incentives by tax credits which,
contrary to Mr Axiotes’ apparent belief, not only do not reduce profits but are
treated as income for accounting purposes so, increase them, and reduce the
risk of the minimum tax applying.
ROBERT MAAS
0 Comments:
Post a Comment
<< Home