Business Rates Revisited
BLOG
197
BUSINESS RATES REVISITED
My friend, Michael Quinlan, has taken
issue with my comments in Blog 192 in relation to rates.
His first point is that if rates are a
tax on occupation, why does he pay rates on his property when it is not occupied,
i.e. it cannot be let. The answer is
that the government want to encourage him to let it. He does not have to pay business rates for
the first three months the property is let (six months, if it is a commercial
or industrial property), but the government do not want him to deliberately
leave it empty. Personally, I wish that
governments would stop using the tax system to achieve non-revenue raising
objectives as this needlessly complicates the system and obscures the fiscal
objective, but this is probably crying for the moon.
Michael asserts that Harry Hyans left
Centre Point empty for years in the early 70s until rents rose. I thought that myth had been fully debunked
years ago. My recollection is that
Centre Point was empty (or rather largely empty) for years because it was a
badly designed building. It had lots of
long narrow offices. It might have been
a great open-plan building, but open-plan was not the norm in the 70s. It was eventually occupied by the CBI, which
was prepared to put up with the poor working environment in order to diffuse
the continuous press comment that the building was being deliberately left
empty.
Michael next points out that rates are
excessive because valuations are carried out at infrequent intervals and become
too high during a falling market. I
agree that five-yearly revaluations are too infrequent and that the system
falls into disrepute when the government defers a revaluation for political
reasons. Yearly revaluations would be
fairer, but probably unacceptably expensive.
But I do not think that the system should be damned for that
reason. There must be some sort of
satisfactory compromise. For example,
values could be indexed in some way in the years between revaluations. That is not wholly satisfactory because of
course values of different properties do not increase at a single rate; indeed,
even where rents rise generally, those in some areas fall.
But I do not think the problem is that
rateable values are too high in a falling market. The rateable values are used to apportion the
overall rate burden over all business, so if rents either rise or fall
proportionately that allocation remains constant. Of course, if at a time of falling rents the
costs of providing local services rises, there is bound to be pain to
businesses. But that is not the fault of
rates; it is because the rising costs have to be paid for somehow.
A bigger problem is that if business A’s
rates are based on say, four-year old values and rents are falling, business A
will squeal, but if rents are increasing, it won’t complain that it is paying
too little. Leaving aside new buildings,
if the stock of buildings is constant and the rate is unchanged (both
unrealistic assumptions in practice of course), if business A’s rental value
has increased, business A benefits from paying too little in rates, but for
business A’s value to rise, business B’s value has to fall, so business B is in
effect subsidising business A. That is
particularly unfair because it happens at a time when business B can least
afford to overpay.
Michael’s next point is that central
government increasingly loads more costs onto local authorities and therefore
onto business rates. I am not sure to
what extent that is true. The business
rate itself, the poundage as it used to be called, is fixed centrally by the
government and, while it increases each year, appears to do so only to reflect
inflation. Local authorities are
reluctant to increase council tax (because that is payable by voters) and
cannot increase business rates (because they have no control over the rate) so
are largely forced to cut services to reflect the reduced funding. Whilst views differ as to whether or not that
is a good thing, it does not increase the rates.
Michael’s final point is not actually
the fault of business rates at all. This
is that if local authorities ban parking, or install parking meters that gobble
up loose change at an astounding rate, in their local High Street, it is hardly
surprising that o one wants to shop there.
That means that at the next revaluation, the business rates from High
Street shops will fall and the local authority will be worse off. Accordingly, why do they do it? I cannot take issue with Michael on that one. However, I doubt that parking charges are what
are killing the High Street. I think it
more likely that, even with free parking, there would in most cases be
insufficient parking space available in the town centre for shoppers. I also suspect that the days of the High
Street as a generalised retail area are long gone, as the out of town
superstores are able to provide a far greater range of products than their
smaller High Street outlets and we are now used to this wider choice.
ROBERT
MAAS