IS THIS THE SORT OF TAX AUTHORITY YOU WANT? - PART 9
BLOG
170
IS THIS THE SORT OF TAX AUTHORITY YOU WANT? – PART 9
We are constantly being told by both
Ministers and HMRC that we have a fair tax system. I am not sure what “fair” means. It seems to me to be a concept that takes its
meaning from the particular circumstances in which fairness falls to be
addressed. However, at a minimum, I
think it implies even-handedness.
In the context of tax I would have
thought that if one pays the tax prescribed by the legislation, one has
fulfilled one’s duty to society. That
always used to be the case. However in
recent years, politicians have asserted a doctrine of tax morality, by which
they mean that it can be immoral to pay the tax prescribed by the legislation
if that does not reflect what they describe as the intention of parliament.
Conceptually, there is a problem here,
insofar as everyone who is familiar with parliamentary procedure knows
parliament does not normally have an intention in enacting tax
legislation. What happens is once the
Finance Bill is published, it is considered in Committees. For a few clause this is a Committee of the
Whole House, but for most of the Bill it is a Committee of around 20 people,
which is roughly 3% of the number of MPs.
Erskine May on Parliamentary Procedure defines the role of such a Committee
as to consider the Bill line by line and to refine it. That happened up to the 1970s. It no longer happens today. A Committee is an opportunity to make
political points. There is little or no
attempt to improve the legislation or even to consider it line by line. It is considered clause by clause but almost
all the debates are on either a motion that “the Clause stand part of the Bill”
(i.e. that it simply be accepted as drafted) or that the Government should
publish a report of the clauses operation (normally within six months and often
well before the clause comes into operation at all).
Accordingly what is in the Finance Bill
may reflect Ministers’ views; it may reflect the draftsman’s view; it may
reflect HMRC’s view. But it certainly
does not reflect the view of Parliament.
Traditionally the courts have sought to
discern the view of Parliament from the wording that Parliament has used in the
legislation. Sadly, in doing so, they
have a nasty habit of arriving at a result that the government of the day
doesn’t like. Accordingly our political
masters have developed a concept that what the law says is not what the law
means if the result cannot have been intended by parliament. They have gone on to introduce the concept of
fairness into tax.
I have no particular problem with either
morality (as long as it is for the taxpayer, not for Mr Osborne or Mr Gauke to
determine what he believes to be moral) or fairness (provided that it is a
two-way street). It does however seem to
me completely unreasonable for either the government or HMRC to be saying, “We
think that taxpayers should refrain from asserting their legal rights when it
is immoral or unfair to do so, but HMRC should enforce the law rigorously, no
matter how immoral or unfair that may be”.
But that seems to me to be the position of both the government and HMRC.
This is well illustrated by two recent
tax cases. The first is Ames v
HMRC. Mr Ames invested in a
company. His investment qualified for income
tax EIS relief. The CGT legislation
provided that if EIS shares are sold after the end of the EIS period and “an
amount of EIS relief is attributable to the shares”, the gain is not
taxable. Unfortunately his income was
less than his personal allowance, so he had no taxable income against which he
could claim EIS relief in the year in which he invested. Mr Ames consoled himself with the fact that he
realised a substantial tax-free capital gain on the shares. “Oh No,” said HMRC, No amount of EIS relief
is attributable to your shares because you had no income against which such
relief could be given. Does anyone
believe that in enacting the EIS legislation, parliament deliberately decided
to give CGT exemption if the shares increased in value and the taxpayer had £1
of income against which the relief could be claimed but there should be no such
exemption if the person happened to have no taxable income in the year he made
the investment? Does anyone think that
is a fair outcome? If the government is
not prepared to treat Mr Ames “fairly” by taxing him only on the basis that
parliament would undoubtedly have adopted if it had considered a person in Mr
Ames position when it introduced the EIS legislation, it seems highly
hypocritical for it to urge those who successfully use artificial tax avoidance
schemes to pay the tax that parliament would have imposed (but didn’t) if it
had contemplated the scheme at the time it passed the legislation.
The next case is Flix Innovations Ltd v
HMRC. The company raised money on the
basis that the shares would qualify for EIS relief. It had in issue a class of valueless non-voting
deferred shares. The shares were
entitled on a liquidation to repayment at par but only after the par value of
the ordinary shares had been repaid.
They had no other rights. The
company then issued the EIS shares.
“Sorry”, said HMRC, “One of the conditions for EIS relief is that the
EIS shares must not have preferential rights.
They have preferential rights over the deferred shares so no EIS relief
is due”.
Did parliament really intend that EIS
relief should not apply if a company were to strip some of its existing shares
of virtually all of their rights prior to an issue of EIS shares so that the
EIS investors would obtain a fair stake in the company? I very much doubt it.
So why didn’t HMRC say, “We will ignore
these valueless shares because they clearly don’t fall within the mischief that
parliament had in mind when it said that EIS shares should not have
preferential rights”? That is what the
government expects taxpayers to do when the law “unfairly” benefits them.
Surely we should either have a fair tax
system or everyone, including the State, should accept that legislation can
give rise to unanticipated results. It
is not reasonable for the State to berate those who benefit from such anomalies
but itself insist on taking those unintended benefits that accrue to the State.
ROBERT
MAAS
0 Comments:
Post a Comment
<< Home