ITS ALL IN THE MIND!
BLOG
201
IT’S ALL IN THE MIND!
I recently attended the Hardman Lecture,
one of the ICAEW Tax Faculty’s annual flagship events that I try not to
miss. The speaker was Paul Johnson, an
economist who is Director of the Institute for Fiscal Studies. He spoke on “Tax, its role in our
future”. But I don’t want to comment on
his talk. There was something he said
and his answer to one of the questions both of which started me thinking about
the gulf that sometimes appears between perception and reality.
The first is student loans. Paul welcomed the fact that the government
has at last recognised that the bad debts on student loans ought to feature as
government expenditure. But in reality
there are no bad debts on student loans; that is because they are not really
loans at all.
The real deal with the student is that
the graduate has to pay the State 9% of his earnings over £25,725 a year. The Office for National Statistics say that
average earnings for August 2019 was £28,184.
However, the average for, say, a 25-year old is likely to be
significantly less. In other words, the
deal is that the student should pay the State 9% of the extra earnings that he
can generate by virtue of his degree. If
his earnings are less than £25,725 (actually if his earnings in a week are less
than £494) he has no obligation to repay anything. The repayments are capped. They stop when the total paid becomes equal
to the initial financial support plus interest thereon. If the aggregate payments after 30 years are
less than that amount, nothing further is payable.
That is not a loan; it is a graduate
tax. But of course there would be uproar
if the government said that they intended to impose a 9% tax on education. Calling it a loan sounds much more acceptable. But a problem with putting a false label on a
product is people start to believe the label.
This can have unfortunate side effects.
For a start, both students and lenders which should know better treat it
as a loan when the student wants to borrow to buy a flat. That is unfair. The “student loan” has no real effect on his
borrowing capacity; its effect is that 9% of the top slice of his earnings is
not available to make mortgage payments, so the lender ought to reduce the
earnings by that 9% in deciding what multiple of earnings it is prepared to
lend.
Similarly, the government should not
bring the “bad debt” into the national accounts. An amount that is never due to be paid is
clearly not a bad debt in any rational interpretation of the word. It should bring into account the whole
expenditure on educating the student while he is at university and should
credit to the national accounts the receipts from graduates. That would really make the national
accounts look sick. But it is better to
face up to the reality, than to disguise it.
The second issue is National
Insurance. Anita Monteith, the Tax
Faculty’s senior manager asked Paul whether he thought that tax and National
Insurance for the employed and self-employed should be brought into line and he
agreed that would be a good idea. I have
a lot of respect for Anita, but not in this instance. They seem to me to be already in line with
one another.
An employer pays 12% NI on the slice of
earnings between £166 and £962 a week. I
make that £4,967.04. He also pays 2% on
the excess over £962 (£50,024 pa). A
self-employed individual pays 9% on profits between £8,632 and £50,000, which
comes to £3,724.12. He also pays £3 a
week Class 2 contribution, so his total NI is £3,880.12. He also pays the same 2% on the excess over
£50,000 as an employee. So he pays
£1,086.92 (£20.90 a week) less than the employee. However, the self-employed individual does
not qualify for jobseekers allowance of £73.10 a week when he is out of work,
so the £1,086 saving could be said to reflect that ineligibility to benefit. Both pay the same income tax, although the
employee pays it only on what he is free to spend, whereas the self-employed
individual also has to pay more income tax on money which he cannot spend as it
is needed to provide capital in the business.
There is also a different treatment of expenses. It is very difficult for an employee to
obtain a deduction for expenses, but that is because HMRC and the government
expect the employer to pay its own business expenses, not require the employee
to pay them out of his salary, and the test for expenses of the employer and
the self-employed is identical.
What Anita and Paul are really concerned
about is the employee’s National Insurance contribution. But that is not a tax on the employee. It gives no insurance benefit to the
employee. If the employer is non-UK
resident, no employer’s contribution is payable even though his UK resident
employee still has to pay the employee’s NI.
The reality is that the employee’s NI
contribution is a payroll tax. Most
economists think that payroll taxes are not a good idea. They discourage employment. If full employment is a good thing (it
probably isn’t actually, but 96% employment is) anything that discourages it is
a bad thing. It also encourages
businesses to look for alternatives to employment, which normally means more
computerisation, which is a good thing only if it is done in such a way that
the displaced workers can readily find other work.
It also distorts the tax burden on
employers, particularly corporate employers.
The government are proud of their 17% headline rate of corporation tax,
which is amongst the lowest for developed countries. But that 17% is a lie. Suppose a company has income of £1million, salary
payments of £600,000 and other expenses of £300,000 and that 90% of its salary
payments attract 13.8% NI. It pays 17%
tax on its profit of £100,000, a mere £17,000.
But that is misleading. It also
pays payroll taxes of 13.8% of 90% of £600,000, which is £74,520. So its real tax burden is £91,520, which is
over 90% of its £100,000. But “the UK is
open for business; move your business to the UK and pay tax of only 91%” is
somewhat less attractive than a 17% rate.
The mis-labelling though creates a
perception that there is an unfair differential between tax and NI on
employment and self-employment. That
perception (I nearly wrote deception, which may be more accurate) – combined
with the fact that the government and HMRC seem happy to allow closely-held
companies to reward work done by their directors by way of dividend (which does
not attract NI at all) rather than salary – is largely responsible both for the
massive growth in personal services companies and the highly complex IR35
legislation which vainly seeks to counter the resultant loss of NI
receipts. That loss is directly
attributable to the government allowing “employers” to avoid having to apply
PAYE and NI by engaging “staff” via personal services companies while at the
same time allowing those companies to escape NI by replacing salary with
dividends.
ROBERT
MAAS
0 Comments:
Post a Comment
<< Home